How strong was the commerce clause argument in the
Affordable Care Act case (National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius)?
I have to say that I sympathize with the conservative
justices’ concern that the commerce clause shouldn’t become the basis for
congressional power over everything. Of course, it wouldn’t be – that is, no
matter what Congress has power to regulate, it can’t regulate anything in
violation of the Bill of Rights. Moreover, just at the moment Congress can
hardly pass legislation at all, on any subject, and so it’s a bit difficult to
say we’re all in peril of congressional overreaching right now. In fact, it’s
difficult to see any Congress ever legislating in true and utter disregard of
the states, from which every member of Congress is elected. Nevertheless, I
agree with the basic idea that liberty is safer if no one unit of government is
too powerful. Moreover, perhaps in part as a result of having studied South
African law from the days before that country’s Parliament was subject to
meaningful constitutional limits, I’m not entirely comfortable with trusting
that Congress just won’t choose to
exercise power once we’ve decided that it could if it wanted to.
So I think the idea that there should be some limits on the
commerce power has appeal. But what’s startling about this case is how
implausible it is as the occasion for finding such limits. Health care is a
huge part of the United States economy, the stuff of interstate commerce every
minute of the day. Moreover, it seems quite clear that if the individual
mandate had not been upheld, the elaborate scheme of the Act would have been
greatly undercut. The various provisions of the Act designed to make health
insurance available at reasonable prices to people with preexisting health
problems – an essential feature of the law – would likely have been
unsustainable without the premiums to be paid by healthy young people
purchasing insurance because of the individual mandate. In fact, the four
dissenters (Scalia, Kennedy, Thomas and Alito) were convinced that without the
individual mandate and the expansion of Medicaid, the whole system would be so
compromised that they would have thrown out the entire statute, every single section.
So not only is health care clearly part of interstate commerce, but the
individual mandate – the portion of the statute evaluated under the commerce
clause – was necessary to the overall regulation of commerce achieved by the
law, and so should have been seen as “necessary and proper” to Congress’
exercise of its power over interstate commerce.
Except for one thing. That was that, as the conservative
justices (including Roberts) saw the matter, what Congress was regulating with
the individual mandate was not activity but inactivity. There was no commerce
to regulate, these justices believed, until the statute forced everyone into
the insurance market by mandating that they get insurance. The conservative
justices insisted that the power to regulate was not the power to create commerce
but the power to manage what already existed, and that Congress had never
previously been allowed to regulate the failure
to engage in interstate commerce.
This argument strikes me as particularly weak. It may well
be that Congress has never regulated commercial non-activity, and
correspondingly that no precedent ever said that Congress could do that. It’s
probably also true that no precedent ever said that Congress could not do it, and that the reason Congress
didn’t regulate inactivity was that doing so wasn’t so deeply integral to a
larger regulatory effort as it was in this case.
Yet one might respond that “inactivity” is simply,
definitionally, beyond the range of both Congress’ commerce power and its
adjunct, the necessary and proper clause. One might, but why? As Justice
Ginsburg says in her separate opinion, dissenting on this issue, similar
efforts were made in the 1930s, notably to limit Congress’ power to regulating
activities with “direct” effects on interstate commerce, while barring Congress
from dealing with activities whose effects, however
large, were merely “indirect.” That idea has long been abandoned, for at
least three good reasons, each applicable here too.
First, the words “direct” and “indirect” don’t appear in the
commerce clause or the necessary and proper clause. However conservative the
justices who employed these terms, they are judicial interjections rather than
part of the constitutional text. “Activity” and “inactivity” are similarly
absent from the constitutional text.
Second, and more or less by design, the concepts of “direct”
and “indirect,” like those of “activity” and “inactivity,” have nothing to do
with the actual impact of what people are doing (or not doing), either its
impact on the economy or – the real point – its effects on their other citizens
and residents of the United States. It isn’t a virtue to be deliberately
disconnected from sensitivity to real impacts.
Third, these words – “direct” and “indirect,” “activity” and
“inactivity” – are pretty deeply obscure. Justice Ginsburg argues at length
that people who don’t buy health insurance are not inactive in the market for health care; they will, on the
contrary, very likely consume health care within the foreseeable future, say 5
years. They may need that health care in a moment, since no one knows when
injury or illness will strike without warning. So they are, as Ginsburg suggests,
actually “active” in the market, via the route of “self-insurance.” For some,
moreover, self-insurance will fail; they will wind up unable to pay for their
health care when they actually need it, and these health care consumers are
every day engaged in a process of free riding on the rest of us. Others – those
whose premiums are so needed in order to pay for the costs of making insurance
widely available to people who can’t currently purchase it – are not free
riding but rather are resisting paying part of society’s bill; but they too may
be seen as actively refusing to purchase, rather than simply being inactive.
When is a “refusal to act” (or, to use another phrase, a “failure to act”)
actually an “activity”? The constitution doesn’t say. Chief Justice Roberts
says that someone who is sitting around and doing nothing is not in the “rest”
market – but we’re a long ways from that case in talking about how people deal
with the inevitability that they will need health care.
All of this makes me feel that it was simply a mistake to
try to draw a line between what the commerce clause reaches and what it doesn’t
that is based on the supposed distinction between “activity” and “inactivity.”
But what about the broccoli argument? It is, after all, true that broccoli
purchases, aggregated across all the consumers in the United States, have a
substantial effect on interstate commerce, and so – as the conservatives said –
the kind of logic I’m endorsing would suggest that the federal government could
order us all to buy broccoli.
I don’t think the government should be able to make us buy
broccoli. (Should it be able to prevent us from buying huge containers of
sugared soft drinks? That’s actually an easier question under the commerce
clause – buying soft drinks is an activity, by any lights, and so regulating
that activity shouldn’t raise any of the questions that mandating insurance
did.) But back to broccoli – I think that heading off this possible extension
of federal power is a matter that deserves attention, and that finding a
coherent rule that does this may not be easy. But broccoli is not this case, as
lawyers say. We are a long ways from broccoli in thinking about how to finance
health care for the American people, an issue of almost overwhelming commercial
and economic import.
So it seems to me, in the end, that the conservatives picked
the wrong case to draw a commerce clause limit in. Limits may be needed, but
they should have been drawn so that this statute fell within them rather than
beyond their bounds. And it would have been good to find limits that avoided
the incoherence of the “activity”/”inactivity” line that is now apparently part
of our constitutional law.
No comments:
Post a Comment